My colleague
Prof. Ralph Clifford is
cited and quoted in
this item from
the Pacific Legal Foundation. The PLF opined with disapproval upon takings problems in which the government essentially exploits the takings power after discounting property value by tax liability, a one-two punch, kicking the owner to the street.
The abuse is compounded by the continuing latitude of governments to line the pockets of private investment with the proceeds of takings, upheld in
Kelo v. New London (2005).
See also the award-winning documentary
Little Pink House (2017), and a
mouth-watering Kelo epilog.
This on the heels of discussion at UMass Law last week of a U.S. Supreme Court
cert. petition filed in
Smyth v. Conservation Commission of Falmouth (Mass. App. Ct. Feb. 19, 2019),
now No. 19-223 (pet. filed U.S. Sept. 19, 2019), in which the Massachusetts Court of Appeals rejected a takings claim upon denial of a building permit. (HT@
Dean Eric Mitnick. The court heard arguments in the case at
UMass Law last year.)
One doesn't have to look far nowadays for abuses of governmental power that are bipartisanly objectionable yet persist to the shameless aim of making the rich richer. I'm presently reading Amor Towles's
A Gentleman in Moscow, a fiction about the aftermath of the Russian revolution; when you're a libertarian and you start thinking "those Bolsheviks weren't all bad," something has gone awfully wrong in America.
Here is an excerpt of
the PLF item:
Uri is a retired 83-year-old Michigan engineer, and in 2014 he
accidentally underpaid, by $8.41, the property taxes on a home he rented
out. But instead of notifying him of the issue and helping him, his
county government seized the home and sold it at auction for $24,500.
The county then kept all the proceeds—leaving Rafaeli with nothing.
All for an 8 buck mistake.
That
may sound like an extreme and unusual case. But in fact, this type of
tax forfeiture abuse, called home equity theft, is completely legal in
13 states.
In Alabama, Colorado, Maine, Massachusetts, Michigan,
Minnesota, New York, North Dakota, Oregon, and Wisconsin, governments
not only keep the value of unpaid property taxes and interest from the
sale of a seized home—they also keep the surplus value rather than
returning it to the property owner. In Arizona, Colorado, Illinois,
Massachusetts, and Nebraska, private investors often reap the gains of
home equity theft.
Here is the abstract of
Prof. Clifford's 2018 study:
|
Prof. Clifford |
The predominant method for collecting delinquent real estate taxes in
Massachusetts is the use of the “tax deed” as authorized by Chapter 60,
Sections 53-54. Under the authorized procedures, each municipality’s
tax collector can execute and record a deed that transfers fee simple
title to the real estate to the municipality subject to the taxpayer’s
statutorily created redemption right. If the redemption right is or
cannot be exercised, all of the taxpayer’s rights in the property, as
well as other’s rights created by encumbrances such as mortgages, are
terminated by the foreclosure process provided for in the statute.
Importantly, the municipality does not obtain title to the taxpayer’s
land by foreclosure; instead, it merely frees itself of any remaining
claim by the taxpayer.
The problem with the tax deed procedure is that it fails to provide both
procedural and substantive due process to the taxpayer. Procedurally,
although adequate notice is given, title to the taxpayer’s real estate
is taken by the government without a hearing. Based on an unreviewed
decision by a municipal tax collector, the taxpayer immediately loses
title to the land. Substantively, by using a tax deed, the municipality
engages in the taking of property without providing reasonable
compensation. The value of the land taken for payment of the tax debt is
not evaluated in the context of the debt owed. Empirical evidence shows
that the property’s value significantly exceeds the debt owed, giving
the municipality the ability to collect almost fifty dollars for every
dollar of delinquent real estate tax owed, on average. Each year,
approximately $56,000,000 is unconstitutionally appropriated from
taxpayers. This article explores these problems.
And here are the questions presented in
the Smyth petition:
In Penn Central Transp. Co. v. N.Y., 438 U.S. 104 (1978), this Court held that Fifth Amendment “regulatory takings” claims are governed by three factors: the “economic impact” of the challenged regulatory action, the extent of interference with a property owner’s “distinct investment-backed expectations” and the “character of the governmental action.” Id.
The Massachusetts Appeals Court applied the Penn Central factors to hold that Respondent Town of Falmouth (Town) did not unconstitutionally take Petitioner Janice Smyth’s (Mrs. Smyth) property by denying a permit to build a home. Mrs. Smyth’s parents purchased the lot in 1975 for $49,000 ($216,000 in today’s dollars), but did not develop it. In the meantime, the entire subdivision was developed. When Mrs. Smyth inherited the lot and sought to build, the Town refused to grant a permit based on regulation post-dating her interest. The denial left Mrs. Smyth’s lot without any possible use except as a “playground” or “park,” and stripped it of 91.5% of its value. Yet, the court below held that none of the Penn Central factors weighed in favor of a taking under these circumstances.
The questions presented are:
1. Whether the loss of all developmental use of property and a 91.5% decline in its value is a sufficient “economic impact” to support a regulatory takings claim under Penn Central.
2. Whether a person who acquires land in a developed area, prior to regulation, has a legitimate “expectation” of building and, if so, whether that interest can be defeated by a lack of investment in construction?
3. Whether the Court should excise the “character” factor from Penn Central regulatory taking analysis.
My Comparative Law class is reading about
democratic deficit in Europe. It's a good time to remember that the study of comparative law can be as much about similarities as differences.